Progress Toward Rational Spectrum Rights: Are We Getting Anywhere?
PDF VersionEllen P. Goodman
Professor of Law, Rutger University - Camden
Analysts from legal, economic, and engineering
disciplines
have supplied plenty of commentary in the past decade on what ails U.S.
spectrum management. We have offered a
number of competing proposals for how to define the rights of spectrum
users to
emit signals, the responsibilities of spectrum users to reject noise,
how
spectrum rights and responsibilities should be recorded, and how
conflicts over
interference ought to be adjudicated. We
have also provided differing views on the proper balance between the
prevention
of conflicting spectrum uses (frequently called ex ante
protections) and
the resolution of conflicting uses after the fact (ex post
dispute
resolution), as well as varying suggestions for public and private
institutional roles. Notwithstanding difference in the details, it
seems that analysts
are converging on some important consensus conclusions.
These include the following: We
need much more spectrum made available for
mobile broadband We need a combination of exclusive rights and
shared rights to access spectrum, recognizing that sometimes we will
want
"easements" or low impact access to spectrum that has otherwise been
assigned
for exclusive use, sometimes we will want commons spectrum for
unlicensed
innovation, and sometimes we will want tightly controlled access for
specific
rights holders More intensive use will and should mean more
conflicts over spectrum use These
conflicts should be prevented before the
fact by some combination of FCC zoning of compatible uses and industry
performance standards These
conflicts should be addressed after the
fact with expedited adjudications and arbitrations, which depend on the
creation of the appropriate administrative apparatus (in both private
and
public institutions) Efficient
conflict resolution requires that
initial entitlements be stated precisely in the license (or
license-free
allocation) at the outset, and be further articulated in what will be
an evolving
"common law" allocating responsibilities for mitigating interference What
the right rule is for allocating
responsibilities in any particular spectrum dispute will depend on the
kind of
services at issue, the relative ability of the parties to address the
problem
at the receiver or the transmitter, and other public interests
(externalities)
that may be implicated ·
Spectrum use entitlements, both initial and
post-dispute, should be made transparent in publically accessible and
user-friendly registries While these conclusions have been gestating,
battles have
played out over the allocation of spectrum for unlicensed and exclusive
use,
and over the modification of existing licenses to allow for more
intensive (and
valued) spectrum use. One cannot say
that spectrum management has changed much over the past decade or that
we have
made a great deal of progress in implementing the conclusions stated
above. Spectrum management is still
pretty much the same as it always has been:
highly conservative, protective of incumbents, without clear
entitlements and dispute resolution procedures, lacking in the
regularity and
transparency that would facilitate secondary markets, and, most
especially,
bogged down in questions of fairness, windfall, strained readings of
the public
interest, and competitive advantage. That said, this Commission has made several
notable recent
decisions to free up spectrum for new uses by modifying existing
entitlements
and mediating between potential spectrum conflicts.
These include the order opening up TV band
"white spaces" available for unlicensed fixed and mobile wireless usage
and the
decision removing obstacles to mobile wireless use of spectrum adjacent
to
satellite radio. There
were some innovations on the spectrum
management front here and they are worth building on.
The most important decision yet to come will
probably concern the reallocation of broadcast spectrum for broadband
use. Things
take longer when no one can be held
accountable for interference. One of
the complications of unlicensed use, however desirable it may be, is
that it's
hard to assign responsibility for interference.
This difficulty buttresses the already existing tendency
towards
conservative allocations and is one of the reasons the White Spaces
decision
took so long. Innovative "zoning,"
revocable certifications and registrations, and a certain amount of
reciprocity
for interference prevention ease this problem.
Under-explored is the role that interference insurance might
play. Failure or inability to deal with the
receiver side of the equation produces sub-optimal entitlements. Whether or not incumbents should have the
obligation to improve receiver performance will depend on many factors,
including the type of network deployed and the state and pace of
technological
innovation. Much more clear is that the
FCC should have the authority to mandate receiver performance, or to
mandate
compliance with industry-set standards. Harmful interference should be a yield sign,
not a stop sign.The FCC continues to use predicted harmful
interference as
a gatekeeper to spectrum entry. The
concept is in effect BOTH a tool to define rights (new entrant may not
cause harmful
interference) AND a tool to assign liability (new entrant is
responsible for
harmful interference it does cause).
Instead, the notion of harmful interference should be, among
other
elements, what gives a spectrum user a "cause of action" to seek
redress. Whether the harm is actually
redressable, and
by what means, should be separate questions. Confusing efficient spectrum use with
distributional issues is recipe for delay.
The public interest in spectrum exploitation and the
public (and
competitor) interests in preventing licensees from getting windfall
benefits
are distinct. Whether or not spectrum
rights should be expanded, who should get to take advantage of expanded
rights,
and what they should have to pay for them are all separate issues and
should be
handled separately, with mechanisms for redistribution of benefits
where
necess Consideration
of values associated with
spectrum use other than efficiency is under-developed. Reallocation
of
broadcast spectrum in particular will touch on values that are baked
into the
current allocation, such as universal service, noncommercial
set-asides, and
distributed access rights. As with
distributional issues, these considerations are conceptually separate
from
efficient spectrum exploitation, but will need to be dealt with.